WTO Impact on Small Farmers of Asian Economies
- Asif Maqbool
- Muhammad Rasheed
- Naeem Qasim
Today, perhaps the greatest threat to small
farmers is free(WTO) trade. And the farmers are fighting back. They have
helped, for instance, to stalemate the Doha round of negotiations of the World
Trade Organization (WTO). This tug of war between farmers and free trade is
nowhere more visible than in Asia.
Asian governments placed the burden of
industrialization on the peasantry during the phase of so-called
developmentalist, industry-first policies. In Taiwan and South Korea, land
reform first triggered prosperity in the countryside in the 1950s, stimulating
industrialization. But with the shift to export-led industrialization in 1965,
there was demand for low-wage industrial labor, so government policies
deliberately depressed prices of agricultural goods. In this way, peasants
subsidized the emergence of Newly Industrializing Economies. Peasant incomes
declined relative to urban incomes, and the resulting stagnation of a
once-vibrant countryside led to massive migration to the cities and a steady
supply of cheap labor for factories. The farmers left in the countryside were
primarily poor and aging, and they formed an increasingly small part of the
national work force.
In Thailand, for instance, a tax on rice exports
insulated the domestic market from price movements in the international market,
depressing the price of rice and reducing the wage costs of non-agricultural
employers. A transfer of real wealth from the countryside to the city took
place every year between 1962 and 1981, except for 1970. Not surprisingly,
despite the image of Thailand as an agricultural superpower, a large percentage
of the rural population remains poor.
In China, millions of peasants died of starvation
during the Great Leap Forward as the government requisitioned grain surplus to
finance Mao Zedong’s super-industrialization drive. The chaos of the Cultural
Revolution allowed peasants to regain a degree of control over production
because the government was in crisis. Following the death of Mao in 1976, Deng
Xiaoping dealt with the crisis by introducing the “household contract
responsibility system.” Each family was given a piece of land to farm, along
with the right to sell what was left over after a fixed proportion of the
produce was sold to the government at a state-determined price. This led to
peasant prosperity that, as in Taiwan, stimulated industrial production to
fulfill rural demand.
But, as in Taiwan, this golden age of the
peasantry came to an end, and the cause was identical: the adoption of
urban-centered, export-oriented industrialization. Primitive capital
accumulation for industry took the form of requisitioning peasant surpluses via
heavy taxation. Currently, the various tiers of the Chinese government foist a
total of 269 different taxes on farmers, along with often-arbitrary
administrative charges. Not surprisingly, in many places, taxes now eat up 15%
of farmers’ income, three times the official national limit of 5%. Not
surprisingly, too, while the economy has been growing at 8-10% a year, peasant
income has stagnated, so that urban dwellers now have, on average, six times
the income of peasants. True indeed is the observation of the rural advocates
Chen Guidi and Wu Chuntao that the urban industrial economy has been built “on
the shoulders of peasants.”
The forcing of peasants to subsidize
industrialization was indeed harsh. But at least trade policies at the time
helped to mitigate the pain by barring agricultural imports that were even
cheaper than local commodities. Practically all Asian countries with
agricultural sectors tightly controlled imports via quotas and high tariffs.
This protective shield, however, was severely eroded when countries signed the
Agreement on Agriculture (AOA) and began joining the World Trade Organization
(WTO) starting in 1995.
As a result, the level of subsidization of
agriculture actually increased in developed countries in the first decade of
the WTO. The total amount of agricultural subsidies provided by the OECD’s
member governments rose from $182 billion in 1995 to $280 billion in 1997, $315
billion in 2001, $318 billion in 2002, and almost $300 billion in 2005. The
United States and the European Union (EU) were spending $9-10 billion more on
subsidies in the early 2000s than they were a decade earlier. For every $100 of
agro-exports from the United States, government subsidies accounted for $20-30.
In the case of the EU, the figure was $40-50. While unsubsidized smallholders
in the developing world had to survive on less than $400 a year, American and
European farmers were receiving, respectively, an average of $21,000 and
$16,000 a year in subsidies.
With massive American and European subsidies
distorting global prices in a downward direction, developing country
agriculture became “non-competitive” under the conditions of WTO-mandated trade
liberalization. As the Food and Agricultural Organization (FAO) notes,
instantaneous import surges following the adoption of the AOA in a number of
developing countries led to “consequential difficulties” for “import-competing
industries.” The report continued, “Without adequate market protection,
accompanied by development programs, many more domestic products would be
displaced, or undermined sharply, leading to a transformation of domestic diets
and to increased dependence on imported foods”. This historic shift to
dependence on food imports was, needless to say, accompanied by the
displacement of millions of peasants.
Even before the AOA took effect, the World Bank
was predicting that Indonesian farmers would lose out under the new regime.
Indeed, since 1995, farmers in rice and other basic commodities have been
marginalized. Meanwhile, competitive pressures induced by trade liberalization
led to the expansion of commercial plantations at the expense of smallholders.
In the Philippines, corn farmers, chicken farmers,
cattle raisers, and vegetable growers were driven to bankruptcy in huge
numbers. In Mindanao, where corn is a staple crop, many farmers were wiped out.
As analyst Aileen Kwa has described, “It is not an uncommon sight to see
farmers there leaving their corn to rot in the fields as the domestic corn
prices have dropped to levels [at which] they have not been able to compete.”
With production stagnant, land devoted to corn across the country contracted
sharply from 3,149,300 hectares in 1995 to 2,150,300 hectares in 2000.
In China, tens of thousands of farmers, including
those growing soybeans and cotton, have been marginalized with China’s entry
into the WTO. Indeed, to maintain and increase access for its manufacturers to
developed countries, the government has chosen to sacrifice its farmers.
According to the Institute of International Economics: “The challenge of
managing the farm sector has grown with China’s WTO commitments in agriculture,
which are more far reaching than those of other developing countries and in
certain respects exceed those of high-income countries. The Chinese government
agreed to reduce tariffs and institute other policies that meaningfully
increase market access; accepted tight restrictions on the use of agricultural
subsidies; and pledged to eliminate all agricultural export subsidies. These
commitments went far beyond those made by other participants in the Uruguay
Round negotiations that led to the WTO’s creation.”
In Sri Lanka, thousands of small farmers staged
street demonstrations to protest the import of chicken parts and eggs, claiming
they were being driven out of business. The FAO concurred, noting that import
surges on major food items like chilies, onions, and potatoes made local
production “precarious, as reflected in the significant drop in areas of
production.”
In India, tariff liberalization, even in advance
of WTO commitments, has translated into a profound crisis in the countryside.
Indian economist Utsa Patnaik has described the calamity as “a collapse in
rural livelihoods and incomes” owing to the steep fall in the prices of farm
products. Along with this has come a rapid decline in consumption of food
grains, with the average Indian family of four consuming 76 kg less in 2003
compared to 1998 and 88 kg less than a decade earlier. The state of Andra
Pradesh, which has become a byword for agrarian distress owing to trade
liberalization, saw a catastrophic rise in farmers’ suicides from 233 in 1998
to over 2,600 in 2002. One estimate is that some 100,000 farmers in India have
taken their lives owing to collapsing prices stemming from rising imports.
It is generally feared that WTO would
impact adversely the economies of developing countries like Pakistan . Developing
countries are concerned with the difficulties of non-implementation of the
existing WTO Agreements and objectives and timetable of the current
negotiations on agriculture, services and market access. It appears that the
developing countries4 would be facing more international
uncertainties and additional hardships in integrating their economies with the
global economy. However, countries which accept these challenges and make
necessary changes will benefit from the WTO agreements. Unfortunately Pakistan has
not been able to raise awareness and understanding about WTO among the general
public, industrialists especially the small and medium enterprises and amongst
the farmers especially the small farmers. In a recent study conducted by PIDE5, it was found out that only 4 percent of general public, 46
percent of exporters and 38 percent of the members of the business community
were aware of the WTO issues and even those who were aware had only rudimentary
knowledge of the issues involved.
The resistance to the new regime so opposed to the
interests of small farmers has come from several sectors. At the international
level, trade liberalization and other anti-agriculture policies led to the
formation of two blocs of developing countries: the Group of 20 and the Group
of 33. The G-20 put the developed countries on notice that, unless they
significantly reduced unfair domestic support for agriculture, there would be
no more concessions on market access. The G-33 demanded exemptions from tariff
liberalization for certain products considered vital to agricultural production
and employment (special products or SPs). They also wanted the right to raise
tariffs and resort to other measures — special safeguard mechanisms (SSMs) — to
protect their products from surges of agricultural imports. When the EU and the
United States refused to compromise on these issues, the WTO’s Fifth
Ministerial Meeting in Cancun in 2003 collapsed.
The Ministerial Declaration of the Sixth
Ministerial Meeting of the WTO in Hong Kong in December 2005 recognized the
right of developing countries to designate SPs and institute SSMs. However, the
U.S. backtracking on this commitment as well as its refusal to significantly
reduce its domestic subsidies led to the collapse of the Doha Round of
negotiations in July 2006. Developing countries simply could not provoke more
discontent among their peasant populations by opening their markets even more
in exchange for cosmetic reductions in the massive EU and U.S. agricultural
subsidies.
The opposition to GE-based agriculture has created
a powerful link between farmers and consumers who are angry at corporations for
marketing genetically modified commodities without proper labeling, thus
denying consumers a choice. In the European Union, a solid alliance of farmers,
consumers, and environmentalists prevented the import of GE-modified products
from the United States for several years. Although the EU has cautiously
allowed in a few GE imports since 2004, 54% of European consumers continue to
think GE food is ”dangerous.” Opposition to other harmful processes such as
food irradiation has also contributed to the tightening of ties between farmers
and consumers, large numbers of whom now think that public health and
environmental impact should be more important determinants of consumer behavior
than price.
More and more people are beginning to realize that
local production and culinary traditions are intimately related, and that this
relationship is threatened by corporate control of food production, processing,
marketing, and consumption. This is why Jose Bove’s justification for
dismantling a MacDonald’s resonated widely in Asia: “When we said we would
protest by dismantling the half-built McDonald’s in our town, everybody
understood why — the symbolism was so strong. It was for proper food against
malbouffe [awful standardized food], agricultural workers against
multinationals. The extreme right and other nationalists tried to make out it
was anti-Americanism, but the vast majority knew it was no such thing. It was a
protest against a form of production that wants to dominate the world.”
Many economists, technocrats, policymakers, and
urban intellectuals have long viewed small farmers as a doomed class. Once
regarded as passive objects to be manipulated by elites, they are now resisting
the capitalist, socialist, and developmentalist paradigms that would consign
them to ruin. They have become what Karl Marx described as a politically
conscious “class-for-itself.” And even as peasants refuse to “go gently into
that good night,” to borrow a line from Dylan Thomas, developments in the 21st
century are revealing traditional pro-development visions to be deeply flawed.
The escalating protests of peasant groups such as Via Campesina, are not a
return to the past. As environmental crises multiply and the social
dysfunctions of urban-industrial life pile up, the farmers’ movement has
relevance not only to peasants but to everyone who is threatened by the
catastrophic consequences of obsolete modernist paradigms for organizing
production, community, and life.
No comments:
Post a Comment